International trade | World Trade | global trade policies | Date of international trade

International trade | World Trade | global trade policies | Date of international trade

Talking about International trade | World Trade | Date of international trade | global trade policies | World Bank Group | import and export | economic relations in international trade

Breaking

Friday 24 January 2014

trade in commercial services

01:06 0
 trade in commercial services

  trade in commercial services
trade in commercial services

Once again, Europe is the world’s biggest trading region,

accounting for over half of commercial services exports and just

under half the world’s imports. Trade in services is similar to

agriculture in that it is highly concentrated among a small group of

countries. The developed countries and emerging Asian economies

account for 85%, with China and India the only developing

countries in the top 20. That said, trade in commercial services

is expanding quickly everywhere. In Africa, for example, services

exports and imports) expanded by 21% and 19% respectively in)

2007, higher than the world averages of 18% and 16%.

Tuesday 21 January 2014

Commercial services in international trade

05:40 0
Commercial services in international trade

 Commercial services in international trade
Commercial services in international trade

Another factor to consider in this type of trade is that it is harder

to measure services and their value than it is to measure goods.

Restaurants and their staff, for example, may not include tips

in their bookkeeping or tax returns. And the spread of Internetbased

services is making the problem of measurement even more

difficult, especially when companies hide their transactions to

avoid paying taxes.

Transportation, travel and “other commercial services” (including



the largest categories. “Other” has been both the largest and the

fastest growing category throughout this decade. Incidentally,

such a broad classification shows the difficulties that can arise in

analysing trade flows and developments.

Monday 20 January 2014

The volume of international trade in services

03:08 0
The volume of international trade in services
 The volume of international trade in services
The volume of international trade in services

The low volume of trade in services compared with merchandise

may seem surprising, given that most jobs in OECD economies and

many other countries are now in (services), and services account for


70% of the total value-added in the economies of OECD countries.

Yet for OECD countries overall, service exports in 2006 accounted

for around 22% of total (exports), for a value of $2.1 trillion (75% of

total world services exports) compared with $7.5 trillion for OECD


Service imports to OECD) countries in 2006 accounted for 19% of)

the total imports, worth $1.9 trillion (70% of total world services

imports) and OECD imports of goods were worth $8.2 trillion.


For a start, many services have to be consumed at the point

of production – hotel rooms or office cleaning, for instance.


is (trade) as defined by mode 3 (“commercial presence”) the value

of such business would not show up in balance of payments data

since these only show cross-border trade. This type of trade is

growing as new domains, such as education, health and municipal

services like waste management, are opened up to international

competition.

Saturday 18 January 2014

Production and international trade

03:51 0
Production and international trade
 Production and international trade
Production and international trade

The last half century has seen an increase in the trade in part

and components, and the related international fragmentation of

production helps explain why trade is growing faster than GDP.

Actual physical production cannot be done without the logistics,

accountancy, banking, personnel management and all the other

services needed to support it. But that doesn’t mean that all of

these elements have to take place in the same location, and many

services tasks are now done elsewhere. Tasks where the higher

wages in the home country are not justified by higher productivity

are the first to go abroad. Call centres are one example. This has

prompted some economists to talk of a new era of trade, driven by

cheaper, more efficient communications and lower trading costs.

By their very nature, some services cannot be done abroad. Others

can. But they can all be “traded”. The WTO’s General Agreement on

Trade in Services (GATS) describes four different ways (“modes”)

of doing this. The first mode covers those situations where the

service provider and client may be in different countries. In the

second mode, the client goes abroad. A third mode involves

a company opening a business abroad to provide services. The

fourth mode concerns individuals who travel to another country to

carry out a task, but not to immigrate. Trade in services is covered

by the GATS, which is defined in more detail in the chapter on the

WTO and trade rounds. So-called “South-South” trade in services

is dealt with in the chapter on trade and development.

Saturday 11 January 2014

Trade in services

06:11 0
Trade in services
 Trade in services
Trade in services

No systematic evidence exists on the factors determining
fragmentation. But data on quality of infrastructure, the institutional
environment and administrative costs indicate that low-income
countries are poorly placed to participate in production networks,
despite their advantage in terms of costs. If it’s hard to get the goods
to international markets on time and to the standard required, low
wages will not persuade companies to invest.
The term globalisation is commonly used to describe the
interconnectedness of our world since 1945 in terms of trade in goods
and services, migration and other factors. However, as the poem in
Chapter 2 illustrates, there is nothing new in all this. People have
been trading ideas and products for millennia. What is distinctive in
trade terms about the last 60 years is the degree to which technology
now enables us to spread the supply chain of many products among
different countries and the speed with which firms can now locate
and relocate the various country links in the chain. Before the 20th
century (trade) consisted mainly of countries importing a series of raw
materials and manufacturing the entire final product at home.

Friday 10 January 2014

Economy and trade costs

11:33 0
Economy and trade costs
 Economy and trade costs
Economy and trade costs

Recent economic literature has also looked at the impact of

falling (trade costs) on the location of production, focusing on

the location of different production stages. In particular, this

strand of literature predicts that a reduction in trade costs leads

to greater fragmentation of production, with firms spreading the

different stages of their production process to different locations.

In other words, it may be more profitable to import components

from different places for final assembly rather than concentrating

production in one country.

Trade costs are only one factor determining the decision to

fragment production. The likelihood of offshoring (moving

part of production to a foreign country) is higher in the case of

standardised tasks where little investment in training and quality

control is needed. In addition, countries with a good institutional

framework, good quality infrastructure and flexible administration

(for example, short times to cross the border or to set up a business)

are more likely to attract foreign firms looking to offshore.

evolution of the economy in international trade

01:36 0
evolution of the economy in international trade
 evolution of the economy
evolution of the economy

At the same time, there are other forces working against

agglomeration, so-called (centrifugal forces) that encourage economic

activity to spread out geographically. (Trade) has a crucial influence

in deciding which tendency will dominate at a given stage in the

evolution of the economy. The expansion of manufacturing requires

attracting labour from agriculture by the possibility of higher wages.

But then countries that are essentially agricultural may start to

develop industry, and offer lower wages than the traditional core

industrial nations. This helps to develop manufacturing in these

less central economies. If trade costs continue to fall, low wages

may prove sufficiently attractive to overcome the disadvantages of

manufacturing goods with a relatively unskilled workforce away

from the main markets.


Literature on the analysis of trade flows

often refers to computable general

equilibrium (CGE) and gravity models.

The CGE models use detailed information

on the structures of selected economies

and policies, and integrate them in a

multi-country, multi-sector, “marketclearing”

framework with a sophisticated

representation of demand and supply

relations.

Market-clearing is the idea that markets

will eventually clear excess supply or

unmet demand. This approach is used for

predictions of the future effects of a set

of economic policies and enables a rich

analysis of trade liberalisation scenarios at

various levels.

In contrast to the gravity approach,

CGE analysis allows direct assessment

of welfare effects of trade reforms.

Each result can be traced back to

theoretical assumptions and the structural


The gravity approach uses historical data

to study the statistical significance and


and other factors, including the effects of


The basic version of the gravity model

(relates the volume of bilateral (trade

flows to the economic size of two trading

countries as well as to economic “distance”

as measured by various trade costs.

This approach can help in understanding

historical trends and in particular to

separate the impact of trade policy changes

from other factors affecting trade volumes.

But it is not directly useful for assessing

the welfare implications or distributional

aspects of trade policy changes (“winners

and losers” in the country concerned).

Incidentally, behind an expression like

analysis of trade flows” there lies a

phenomenal amount of data collection and

processing. The gravity model analyses this

chapter draws on, by OECD economists

Kowalski and Shepherd, involved processing

1.5 million lines of data.

48 (OECD Insights: (International Trade

Although there has been some decline in the share of

manufacturing output from the core group of industrial countries

over the past quarter of a century, this decline has been relatively

small. These countries accounted for about 86% of world

manufacturing output in 1976, and in 2002, their share was still

about 81%. This focus on manufacturing as a whole may, however,

hide changes in specific sectors. In the case of iron and steel, for

example, the core’s share has fallen from more than 70% to about

50% of global output. The takeover of the Anglo-Dutch steel group

Corus by Indian-based Tata Steel in 2007 shows how multinationals

originating in developing countries are starting to have an impact

Thursday 9 January 2014

Modelling trade flows

06:21 0
Modelling trade flows

trade flows
trade flows

Literature on the analysis of trade flows

often refers to computable general

equilibrium (CGE) and gravity models.

The CGE models use detailed information

on the structures of selected economies

and policies, and integrate them in a

multi-country, multi-sector, “marketclearing

framework with a sophisticated

representation of demand and supply

relations.

Market-clearing is the idea that markets

will eventually clear excess (supply) or

unmet demand. This approach is used for

predictions of the future effects of a set

of economic policies and enables a rich

analysis of (trade) liberalisation scenarios at

various levels.

In contrast to the gravity approach,

CGE analysis allows direct assessment

of welfare effects of trade reforms.

Each result can be traced back to

theoretical assumptions and the structural


The gravity approach uses historical data

to study the statistical significance and

magnitude of relationships between trade

and other factors, including the effects of


The basic version of the gravity model

(relates the volume of bilateral (trade

flows to the economic size of two trading

countries as well as to economic “distance”

as measured by various trade costs.

This approach can help in understanding

historical trends and in particular to

separate the impact of trade policy changes

from other factors affecting trade volumes.

But it is not directly useful for assessing

the welfare implications or distributional

aspects of (trade policy) changes (“winners

and losers” in the country concerned).

Incidentally, behind an expression like

analysis of trade flows” there lies a

phenomenal amount of data collection and

processing. The gravity model analyses this

chapter draws on, by OECD economists

Kowalski and Shepherd, involved processing

1.5 million lines of data

Wednesday 8 January 2014

Agglomeration effects and global value chains

08:51 0
Agglomeration effects and global value chains

 Agglomeration effects and global value chains
global value chains

Despite globalisation of (supply chains and sales), many industries

tend to be concentrated in certain places or locales, suggesting

that there are economic benefits from firms being located in close

proximity to one another. The concentration of computer-related

activities in California’s Silicon Valley is one example, but the

phenomenon is not new. The textiles sector has been clustered

around the same areas of Italy for centuries, for instance.

Under certain economic conditions, geographic concentration

increases the productivity of all the firms located in a particular

place and it makes their total output larger than if each one had

been operating in a different region. These “agglomeration effects”

occur because workers, and thus their skills and knowledge,

move between sectors and geographical regions and because one

manufacturing firm can use components supplied by a neighbour

(“intermediate inputs”) in its own production. Likewise, services

can be provided more efficiently to firms that are near each other.

There are also a number of benefits that are hard to quantify but no

less real, such as the informal networks of researchers and other

specialists that emerge from social contact.

Sunday 5 January 2014

Volumes in international trade

05:14 0
Volumes in international trade


There has been a spectacular increase in the number of global

supply chains created in recent years and in the volumes passing

through existing chains. One of the forces driving this growth

has been cheaper, more efficient communications and office

technology. This enables multinationals and strategic alliances

of firms to effectively split up the supply chain and produce

increasing numbers of components in different countries according

to comparative advantages. However, there are other forces at play.

The price of oil affects transport costs and, accordingly, the optimal

locations for production in relation to final markets. These types

of influences are referred to as (real economy) forces.

The crisis in global financial markets that began in mid-2007

is a good reminder that the real economy and real trade are also


46 (OECD Insights: (International Trade

(system. The crisis involved volatile changes in (investment

patterns around the world and associated volatile exchange rate

movements that made it very difficult for multinationals to plan

future developments with their global supply chains. Reduced

demand from (trading) partners had repercussions everywhere,

leading to cutbacks in output from factories not only in the OECD

countries but also in China and the other emerging economies.

One of the reasons for this turmoil was the availability of

cheap finance in selected OECD countries after 2001. This led

to riskier (investments) by OECD firms in emerging markets than

would otherwise have been undertaken. In short, global supply

chain expansion after 2001 was very likely much higher than will

be the case over the next decade, and we are likely to see some

contraction because the cost of capital (the interest rates companies

have to pay) has risen. When the crisis struck in 2007 there was a

flight to financial safety and some closure of productive capacity

in particular economies. Financial markets can have important

(effects on the real (trading economy.

Saturday 4 January 2014

Supply chains in international trade

06:02 0
Supply chains in international trade
 Supply chains in international trade
Supply chains in international trade

Supply chains have become much more complex in recent

decades. The computer chip manufacturer, Intel, might

commission a Swedish firm of engineers to design a new chip. The

design is emailed to a chip manufacturer in Taipei who exports

 45  (OECD Insights: (International Trade

the chips to a Malaysian circuit board manufacturer who exports

the board to Ireland which, in turn, exports the computers to the

EU with after-sales service provided by a call centre in Bangalore,

India. If you included all the actors and steps needed to make a

computer, the description would fill a few pages of this book. This

makes describing the (trade) in such products difficult. In 2006,

computers were the highest valued export item from China and

digital integrated circuits were one of China’s largest imports. To

further complicate matters, digital integrated circuits were also

one of China’s largest export products. In fact, after oil, integrated

circuits were the second largest world export item in 2006.

A look at national statistics on manufacturing shows just how

important components have become. In the United States, the

average share of components in the output of the manufacturing

sector was 35% while in the nonmanufacturing sector the figure

was less than 9%. The ratios are quite similar in the other major

OECD countries. In Germany, the ratio was 40.8% in manufacturing

to 8.5% in nonmanufacturing. In emerging (economies), such as

Brazil and China, the share of manufactured intermediates in

the manufacturing sector was between 40% and 50%. Within

manufacturing itself, the sectors with the highest share of use of

components in the OECD countries are motor vehicles (58.6%)

and office, accounting and computing machinery (54.3%). For the

emerging economies, the sectors with the highest share of use of

components were electrical machinery and apparatus (55.8%) and

motor vehicles (53.1%).